[Mb-civic] What is America's neutral interest rate? The Economist

Michael Butler michael at michaelbutler.com
Mon Dec 20 09:57:22 PST 2004


 


 Articles by subject: Topics: Economics




ECONOMICS FOCUS

 Economics focus 

Aiming for a happy medium

Dec 16th 2004 
>From The Economist print edition


What is America's neutral interest rate?


THE decision by America's Federal Reserve to raise the federal funds rate by
a quarter of a percentage point, to 2.25%, on December 14th should have
surprised no one. The Fed has nudged rates up in quarter-point steps at each
of its last five meetings, and makes no secret of its intention to carry on
doing so for a while yet. Its chairman, Alan Greenspan, said recently that
anyone who has not prepared for higher interest rates is ³obviously desirous
of losing money.² Once again the Fed said this week, in the statement
accompanying the interest-rate increase, that it ³believes that policy
accommodation can be removed at a pace that is likely to be measured.²

By any calculation, America's real (ie, inflation-adjusted) short-term
interest rates are still extremely low. The Fed's favourite gauge of
inflation, the rate of increase of the core personal consumption expenditure
deflator, was 1.5% in the year to October, implying a real interest rate of
only 0.75%. According to another measure, the University of Michigan's
estimate of expected inflation over the next year, now 3%, the real fed
funds rate is still negative.

Naturally Swedish

So how high might the fed funds rate go? It is commonly agreed both on Wall
Street and in Washington that rates are heading back towards a ³neutral²
level. The notion of a neutral (or ³natural²) rate of interest was developed
by Knut Wicksell, a Swedish economist writing about a century ago. Wicksell
saw this rate as one that was consistent with stable prices and that
balanced the supply of and demand for capital.

 In its modern incarnation, the neutral rate is the real, short-term
interest rate consistent with stable inflation and an economy that is
growing just in line with its potential: it keeps the pot cooking, without
either boiling over or losing heat. If the real interest rate is below
neutral level, monetary policy is loose: if above, policy is contractionary.
Several monetary-policy rules of thumb (notably the Taylor rule, named after
John Taylor, an economist who is now an official in America's Treasury
Department) rely heavily on the idea. The neutral rate is also implicit in
the Fed's explanation of its strategy. When it speaks of removing
³accommodation² it is, in effect, saying that real rates are below their
neutral level.

So much for the theory. What, in practice, is the neutral rate?
Unfortunately, the real rate that would keep the economy growing in line
with potential and inflation stable cannot be measured directly. It has to
be inferred from the actual, nominal rate, the current level of output,
estimates of the trend rate of growth and measures of expected inflation.
Some economists like to estimate the real federal funds rate over long
periods of time and use that as a proxy for the neutral rate. Over the past
40 years, for instance, this has averaged around 3%. Because this period
spans several recessions and booms, as well as rising and falling inflation,
this average might be a fair guess at the rate of interest consistent with
trend growth and stable prices. If the neutral rate is 3%, this implies that
the Fed might raise rates by at least a further two, and maybe more than
three, percentage points in all.

However, the number varies with the time period chosen. If it includes the
1950s, for example, when rates were low, the average is pulled down. Another
problem with this approach is that it assumes the natural rate to be
constant. Given the changes in America's economy over the years, that may be
a stretch.

 More sophisticated approaches estimate the neutral rate using statistical
techniques that take into account not only nominal interest rates and
inflation, but also variations in output. One method relates the neutral
rate to trend growth, and adjusts it when GDP diverges from its trend. In
this way, Thomas Laubach, a Fed economist on leave at the OECD, and John
Williams, an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, found
that America's neutral real rate has fluctuated widely, ranging from just
over 1% (in the early 1990s) to a little more than 5% (in the late 1960s).
Analysis in the OECD's recent Economic Outlook puts the neutral real rate at
just over 2% in the third quarter of 2004‹implying that the fed funds rate
is now at least a point or two below neutral.

 A further snag, though, is that revisions to economic statistics, which are
frequent and inevitable, can change estimates of the neutral rate
substantially. According to the OECD, America's neutral real rate of
interest in 2002, based on past data alone, was estimated at more than 3%.
But if more recent numbers for inflation and output growth are fed in, the
estimate drops to just over 2%. Two economists at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City, Todd Clark and Sharon Kozicki, looked at these problems
recently and concluded that it was ³very difficult² to rely on model-based
estimates in analysing current policies.

Some at the Fed share this concern. Roger Ferguson, the Fed's vice-chairman,
argued recently that not only was the neutral rate hard to pinpoint, but
that there were several reasons why it might, temporarily, depart from its
long-run equilibrium. For instance, it might have tumbled in the aftermath
of the stockmarket bubble. Other factors, such as Americans' need to save
more or the withdrawal of fiscal stimulus, might continue to pull down the
neutral rate today. Mr Greenspan, asked by a senator in July where America's
neutral rate lay, replied, ³We don't know what neutrality is until we get
there.²

And maybe not even then. For now, Fed officials can head for neutrality,
even while acknowledging that they do not really know where it is. A nominal
fed funds rate of 2.25% is still below any sensible estimate of neutrality.
But as the nominal rate creeps upwards, monetary-policy judgments will
become increasingly difficult. However attractive the theory of a neutral
rate, it will not be of much practical help.



 Copyright © 2004 The Economist Newspaper and The Economist Group. All
rights reserved.



More information about the Mb-civic mailing list